Sunday, June 17, 2007

letter to the editor, responding to Hill's update on PAYGO

I appreciate Baron Hill's frequent efforts to keep his constituents informed of his activity in Congress. But his most recent letter left me confused.

First, Rep. Hill wrote about instituting pay-as-you-go (PAYGO) budgeting-- "a rule requiring that the federal government live within its means"-- in the first few weeks of the 110th Congess. But then he said that he had recently introduced legislation that would reinstitute "statutory PAYGO rules". What's the difference? And does this mean that we won't have a budget deficit next year?

Second, Rep. Hill referred to budget surpluses in the 1990s. But all except one of those were a function of record-keeping shenanigans that moved Social Security from off-budget to on-budget.

Further, he attributed the surpluses to PAYGO rules. But that's quite unlikely. Such "rules" have not been effective in curbing Washington DC's appetite to spend. Does anyone remember the Gramm-Rudman-Hollings "balanced-budget" legislation of the 1980s?

Instead, the top reason for reduced federal deficits in the 1990s (and higher deficits in the 2000s and especially the 1980s) was changes in military spending-- at the height of the Cold War, after the Cold War, and post-9/11.

Third, Rep. Hill referred to the Democratic Blue Dog Coalition as "fiscally conservative". To be accurate, he must have meant that the Dogs are fiscally conservative in comparison to most other Democrats. There have been few fiscally conservative Republicans in Congress over the past decade-- and Democrats are rarely an improvement in that category.

For example, in this year's budget cycle, the Democrats have proposed $23 billion more in spending than the big-spending President George Bush, including an extra $17 billion on the war-funding bill. That works out to an additional $300 from the average family of four in higher taxes now or in the future-- and is hardly the epitome of fiscal conservatism.

With respect to Rep. Hill in particular: he's given D's or F's by the National Taxpayers Union on his votes for government spending; the National Journal rated him at the 36th percentile; and Citizens Against Government Waste gave him a 13% (in the category of "hostile" to taxpayers). In my book, those aren't good grades.

If Rep. Hill is going to title his legislation the "Fiscal Honesty and Accountability Act", he should start with more honesty about his fiscal views. If not, voters should provide the accountability in the next election.

Hill's letter:
http://www.tribtown.com/onset?id=2558&template=article.html

my response:
http://www.tribtown.com/onset?id=2557&template=article.html

Wednesday, June 13, 2007

Don’t Drink (Milk) and Drive—It’s too Expensive…

After a bike ride with our boys two weeks ago, my wife and I went to Kroger’s and were surprised to find milk at $3.35 per gallon. High gas prices have received a lot of attention in recent months. And the price of gas is much more important to the economy as a whole. But at least in our family, high milk prices are just as troubling. We don’t drive that much and with four growing boys, we drink a lot of milk. Putting it another way: a drive to the store to buy milk has become doubly painful.

The reasons for high gas prices are well-documented: high oil prices (connected to OPEC and problems in the Middle East—although a bit lower recently with the perception of increased political stability in Nigeria), increasing demand (here and abroad), domestic supply restrictions (limits on drilling for oil and constructing refineries), environmental regulations that increase costs and fragment the market, and disruptions to refinery capacity (most recently, in Venezuela, Louisiana, and Delaware).

The reasons for high milk prices are more obvious and ironically, are connected to our problems with energy. Higher grain prices (connected to the push for biofuels like ethanol) make it more costly to feed the cows. And higher fuel costs make milk more costly to transport.

Comparing the two goods, consumers are far more flexible with respect to milk. We have few close substitutes for gas (carpool, walk, stay at home), but many substitutes for milk (water, soda, juice). As a result, there is less upward pressure on the price of milk than on gas.

But the market structure for gasoline is much more competitive. It is available at more locations and the prices are prominently posted outside. So, deviations from the “market price” can be punished by customers as they simply travel to the next gas station.

In contrast, it is not surprising that milk prices would vary more, since price checking requires much more effort. In addition, milk is typically bought a few gallons at a time and is usually one of many things bought on a trip to the store. So, consumers don’t register as much concern about its price.

As an example: the day I wrote this essay, the price for 2% milk was $3.51 at the Clarksville Wal-Mart, and in Jeffersonville, $3.49 at Kroger’s ($3.09 if you have their card), $3.29 at Thornton’s, $3.19 at Sav-a-Lot, $3.12 at Meijer’s, and $2.79 at Aldi’s.

What can the government do about this sad state of affairs? Nothing has been proposed in the market for milk yet. But for gasoline, legislators in the U.S. Congress have been busy pushing a law on “price gouging”. (HR1252 passed the House with bi-partisan support; the companion bill S357 is now under consideration in the Senate.)

What are the effects of such price regulations? In the context of significant monopoly power (as with electricity), a price ceiling prevents the monopolist from exploiting his market power. As long as the ceiling is set at a reasonable level above “costs”, then the producer will earn an adequate rate of return and the consumer will be protected.

But in the context of competitive markets, price regulations distort a well-functioning market and cause problems for consumers, producers, and society as a whole. An artificially low price will decrease short-term rationing and long-term conservation by consumers—exactly the sort of behavior we should encourage if we’re concerned about “dependence” on energy. Low prices also diminish the incentives to produce and to innovate.

The net result is a “shortage”—quantity demanded will exceed quantity supplied at the regulated price. We saw this in the 1970s with long gas lines, odd rationing schemes (in Virginia, odd-numbered license plates could only buy gas on Monday, Wednesday or Friday), and gas stations routinely running out of gas.

High prices are painful, but poor policy is worse. As with most other government interventions, price restrictions are economically problematic but politically attractive—when the public doesn’t understand their consequences.